‘Hubrisk’ (hubris+risk) and the Greek Crisis

The Eurozone’s problems are political as well as economic. The European leaders establishing the euro were, according to this column, guilty of putting political desire above economic reality. Their successors now trying to resolve the sovereign debt crisis are repeating that mistake, with potentially devastating consequences.

What makes the European sovereign debt crisis so intractable is that it is not just another crisis. It is two crises in one: A sovereign debt crisis and a policy response crisis. It is the latter which is doing the real damage.

The underlying direct causes are well known. The political desire for strong ties between European countries drove forward the European common market and the monetary union. History tells us that the success of such unions hinges critically on several factors, most importantly a common fiscal policy (Bordo et al 2011 on this site).

In the absence of these conditions, a monetary union is set to fail. The Maastricht criteria was devised by European leaders to avoid failure, but they then wasted no time in ignoring their own design.

By ignoring the necessary conditions, the European leaders who created the euro were guilty of hubris. Their decisions were not rooted in a pragmatic determination for a common good but rather in their own personal political ability to implement a monetary union. This moment of weakness is now the biggest threat to European integration.

This problem was compounded by the prevailing view that sovereign risk had somehow been eliminated – a view encouraged by European banking regulations stipulating that sovereign debt is risk-free. This both acts as a tax on other creditors and also sends a powerful signal. Interestingly, Greek debt is still considered risk-free by the regulators.

Misunderstanding the Greek problem

The European policymakers have consistently misread the nature of the Greek crisis – again letting hubris dominate their crisis response. Many countries have faced similar difficulties as Greece, and the EU leaders could have consulted those with first-hand knowledge of sovereign crisis management (the IMF for example). Instead they repeated mistakes made elsewhere.

The leaders do recognise the common fiscal policy problem, and have contingency plans for a Greek exit from the euro. What they have not done is learn from other sovereign debt crises, and instead let politics get in the way of minimising the economic damage to Europe.

This continues. Now the European policymakers believe that Greece can manage with debt to GDP of 120% – the level Italy currently manages with difficulty. Other crises would tell them this is wishful thinking. The Greek debt tolerance is closer to the Argentinean level of 40% and the extreme austerity is not going to make that better.

The crisis resolution process shows the same familiar signs of further hubris risk. The direct financial cost of a Greek default is quite trivial in the European context. Total Greek debt is around €350 billion, but the EU GDP is €15 trillion, so a total bailout of Greece would only cost the EU around 2.3% of its GDP. The cost of not solving the problem is an order of magnitude higher, estimated in my research with Casper de Vries (Danielson and de Vries 2011) to be 22% of European GDP.

Greece will end up costing its creditors most of the €350 billion. Better to come to that realisation now, and let both the Greeks and the European economy get on with rebuilding. Extreme austerity and parcelling out bailouts will only make it worse.

It is hard to see the objective of the European authorities. Perhaps they want to make sure that anybody receiving bailouts will have to suffer so much that nobody else will be tempted to get into the same situation. Or perhaps they want to use this as a means to create a proper European central government – a transfer union.

Regardless of the motivation, the costs not only to Europe but also to the world are too high. By letting political desire triumph over economic reality, the EU authorities are yet again guilty of hubrisk, the risk of hubris.

References

•Bordo, Michael, Lars Jonung, and Agneiska Markiewicz (2011), “A fiscal union for the euro: Some lessons from history”, VoxEU.org, 21 September.
•Danielsson, Jon and Casper de Vries (2011), “The Macro Costs and Benefits of a Sovereign Greek Default”, EuroIntelligence, 3 October.

Disclaimer: This page contains affiliate links. If you choose to make a purchase after clicking a link, we may receive a commission at no additional cost to you. Thank you for your support!

About Jon Danielsson 5 Articles

Affiliation: London School of Economics

Jon Danielsson has a Ph.D. in the economics of financial markets, from Duke University, and is currently a reader in finance at the London School of Economics.

His research interest include financial risk modelling, regulation of financial markets, models of extreme market movements, market liquidity, and financial crisis.

He has published extensively in both academic and practitioner journals, and has presented his work in a number of universities, public institutions, and private firms.

Visit: LSE

Be the first to comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.


*

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.